How creditors came to wield unprecedented power over heavily indebted countries―and the dangers this poses to democracy
The European debt crisis has rekindled long-standing debates about the power of finance and the fraught relationship between capitalism and democracy in a globalized world. Why Not Default? unravels a striking puzzle at the heart of these debates―why, despite frequent crises and the immense costs of repayment, do so many heavily indebted countries continue to service their international debts?
In this compelling and incisive book, Jerome Roos provides a sweeping investigation of the political economy of sovereign debt and international crisis management. He takes readers from the rise of public borrowing in the Italian city-states to the gunboat diplomacy of the imperialist era and the wave of sovereign defaults during the Great Depression. He vividly describes the debt crises of developing countries in the 1980s and 1990s and sheds new light on the recent turmoil inside the Eurozone―including the dramatic capitulation of Greece’s short-lived anti-austerity government to its European creditors in 2015.
Drawing on in-depth case studies of contemporary debt crises in Mexico, Argentina, and Greece, Why Not Default? paints a disconcerting picture of the ascendancy of global finance. This important book shows how the profound transformation of the capitalist world economy over the past four decades has endowed private and official creditors with unprecedented structural power over heavily indebted borrowers, enabling them to impose painful austerity measures and enforce uninterrupted debt service during times of crisis―with devastating social consequences and far-reaching implications for democracy.
Die Inhaltsangabe kann sich auf eine andere Ausgabe dieses Titels beziehen.
Jerome Roos is an LSE Fellow in International Political Economy at the London School of Economics. He regularly provides commentary on world politics and current affairs for various international media.
List of Tables, Figures, and Boxes, vii,
Acknowledgments, xi,
Introduction. The Sovereign Debt Puzzle, 1,
PART I. THE THEORY OF SOVEREIGN DEBT,
CHAPTER 1. Why Do Countries Repay Their Debts?, 21,
CHAPTER 2. A Critical Political Economy Approach, 40,
CHAPTER 3. The Structural Power of Finance, 50,
CHAPTER 4. Three Enforcement Mechanisms, 68,
PART II. A BRIEF HISTORY OF SOVEREIGN DEFAULT,
CHAPTER 5. The Making of the Indebted State, 85,
CHAPTER 6. The Internationalization of Finance, 95,
CHAPTER 7. From Great Depression to Financial Repression, 109,
PART III. THE LOST DECADE: MEXICO (1982–1989),
CHAPTER 8. Syndicated Lending and the Creditors' Cartel, 125,
CHAPTER 9. The IMF's "Triumphant Return" in the 1980s, 137,
CHAPTER 10. The Rise of the Bankers' Alliance, 147,
CHAPTER 11. "The Rich Got the Loans, the Poor Got the Debts", 158,
PART IV. THE GREAT DEFAULT: ARGENTINA (1999–2005),
CHAPTER 12. The Exception That Proves the Rule, 173,
CHAPTER 13. From IMF Poster Child to Wayward Student, 185,
CHAPTER 14. The Rise and Fall of the Patria Financiera, 194,
CHAPTER 15. "Even in a Default There Is Money to Be Made", 206,
PART V. THE SPECTER OF SOLON: GREECE (2010–2015),
CHAPTER 16. The Power of Finance in the Eurozone, 225,
CHAPTER 17. Anatomy of a "Holding Operation", 235,
CHAPTER 18. The Establishment Digs In, 251,
CHAPTER 19. The Socialization of Greece's Debt, 261,
CHAPTER 20. The Defeat of the Athens Spring, 274,
Conclusion. Shaking Off the Burden, 298,
Appendix. A Word on Methodology, 311,
Notes, 315,
References, 355,
Index, 385,
Why Do Countries Repay Their Debts?
The study of international government finance has long been plagued by a seemingly irreconcilable paradox. In theory, a sovereign debt contract is little more than an ownership title expressing a claim on part of the state's future tax revenues. But since the counterparty in question is by definition always a sovereign power — whose actions have legal force within a given territory and whose privileges include the ultimate authority to ordain and rescind laws — this immediately raises the question of how such contractual claims are enforced in practice. In the absence of a world government or a higher legal authority capable of enforcing cross-border debt contracts and compelling national governments to live up to the letter of their prior commitments, a country that is either unwilling or unable to meet its financial obligations should in theory be able to default on its external debts without repercussions. Seeing that the servicing of interest on international loans effectively constitutes a wealth transfer from the debtor to its foreign creditors, and assuming that government representatives always act rationally in defending the national interest, we would expect distressed borrowers in particular to suspend foreign debt servicing much more frequently than they actually do.
We have already seen how, at the extreme, the logic prescribed by the assumptions of neoclassical economics would therefore mean that a self-interested government should try to borrow as much as possible before repudiating its accumulated external debts in total. If all sovereign borrowers displayed such opportunistic behavior in face of their international obligations, rational lenders would assess the risks and simply refuse to disburse further credit, causing global capital markets to collapse and external debt to disappear altogether. Yet this is clearly not what happens. If anything, the opposite is the case: global capital markets have been thriving ever since the 1970s, and heavily indebted peripheral countries generally do repay their debts, forking over hundreds of billions of dollars in interest payments to their rich-country creditors every year (see figure 1.1), even if they have to go through great pains to remain current on their foreign obligations. As the renowned sovereign debt lawyer Lee Buchheit puts it, "conventional wisdom is that sovereigns will rarely, if ever, default on their external debts in circumstances where it is clear that they have the capacity to pay." Economists at the IMF recognize that distressed borrowers appear to prefer avoiding default "even if that implies running down reserves, shortening the maturity of the debt, and ceding part of their economic policy sovereignty to multilateral institutions." If, for whatever reason, a government finds itself unable to repay its debts in full or on time, it will generally prefer to negotiate an orderly settlement with its creditors over a unilateral suspension of payments. In practice, it therefore remains extremely rare for countries to simply stop paying, let alone to repudiate their obligations outright.
In the economics literature, this striking puzzle at the heart of international lending has long been known as the "enforcement problem" of cross-border debt contracts: clearly there is some kind of cross-border enforcement at work, but the precise mechanism through which it operates is not immediately observable, and economists still do not understand how exactly it works. Apparently most governments do consider default to be costly, preferring to impose painful austerity measures on their own citizens instead. But why is this so? Over the past three decades, this question has inspired a number of hypotheses about the precise costs of default and the exact enforcement mechanisms of debtor compliance. In the resultant debates, four explanations emerged, centering on (1) the borrower's long-term reputation; (2) legal and trade sanctions; (3) democratic institutions; and (4) spillover costs, respectively. Yet despite the important advances that have been made by a new wave of sovereign debt scholarship in recent years, the economics literature is still at pains to answer the most basic question of all: how can external sovereign debt even exist in the first place?
In this chapter, I will briefly discuss the four conventional explanations of debtor compliance found in the economics literature and assess their validity in light of the available evidence. Since economists were the first to identify the puzzle at the heart of this book, it is important to take a closer look at why their abstract theoretical models have so far struggled to account for real-world outcomes. Given the somewhat specialist nature of these debates, the lay reader may want to skip this theoretical discussion and delve straight into the politics and history of sovereign debt in subsequent chapters.
Reputation: The Threat of Long-Term Market Exclusion
The sovereign debt puzzle outlined in the introduction really became an issue of interest for economists only in the late 1970s and early 1980s. The wave of sovereign debt defaults during the Great Depression had caused global capital markets to freeze up for the next forty years, and it was not until after the emergence of the Eurodollar markets in the 1960s and the eventual collapse of the Bretton Woods regime in 1973 that capital really began to flow across borders again. This in turn led to renewed scholarly interest in international lending. The first paper to systematically identify the fundamental paradox at the heart of the sovereign debt puzzle was the aforementioned theoretical contribution by Eaton and Gersovitz, who argued that countries ultimately honor their foreign obligations because they are concerned about their long-term reputation as borrowers. In this reputational model, governments borrow in order to smooth out consumption in the event of unforeseen shocks on the economy, giving them an inherent incentive to repay in order to retain access to international capital markets. "Should the country refuse to repay," Eaton and Gersovitz write, "we assume that it faces an embargo on future loans by private lenders and that this embargo is permanent." In short, countries honor their debts because repudiating them would leave them "forever unable to use international borrowing to smooth absorption across periods of varying income." In a somewhat less restrictive formulation, governments may still be able to access foreign credit following a default, but face significantly higher borrowing costs than their more compliant counterparts, as lenders assess the country's past repayment record and become more skeptical about its capacity to repay in the future, charging a higher risk premium to reflect these lingering fears of potential nonpayment. Schematically, we can represent the causal mechanism at the heart of this account as follows:
[FIGURE OMITTED]
From a quick glance at this visualization, it immediately becomes apparent that the reputation hypothesis hinges on two key assumptions: first, that lenders can and do act rationally and monolithically in their refusal to extend further credit in the event of a default; and second that they actively discriminate between sovereign borrowers on the basis of their past repayment records and demand a higher risk premium from borrowers with a history of default. When it comes to the three case studies undertaken as part of this research project, neither of these assumptions appears to hold up against the empirical evidence.
On the first point, it turns out that the countries that defaulted in the 1930s did not borrow systematically less in the 1970s, nor did they borrow on terms different from nondefaulters. While Latin American borrowers faced severely restricted credit access in the decades following the defaults of the 1930s, the effect was just as strong for a compliant borrower like Argentina, which did not default, as it was for the other countries that did. In fact, when international lending was resumed in the 1970s, there was no noticeable difference in borrowing costs between past defaulters and nondefaulters. Lenders were eager to let bygones be bygones; what mattered was not the historical repayment record of individual sovereign borrowers, but the immediate prospect of easy profits. The evidence from the 1980s therefore points in the direction of a relatively myopic investor attitude towards risk assessment, which was perhaps most blatantly expressed in the statement by Citibank CEO Walter Wriston, just before the crisis broke out, that "countries don't go bust." Angel Gurría, the current secretary general of the OECD who served as Mexico's director of public credit during the 1980s, recounts that "the banks were hot to get in" ahead of the crisis of 1982. "They showed no foresight. They didn't do any credit analysis. It was wild. ... We just issued promissory notes. We were selling them like hotcakes." For foreign creditors, "the prospect of default seemed too extraordinary to consciously consider."
This pattern of investor myopia was repeated in the lead-up to the Argentine default. If investors were really driven by past repayment records in their lending decisions, they should have remembered the country's reputation as a "debt-intolerant" serial defaulter. Instead, by the mid-1990s, Wall Street had embraced Argentina — by far the most recalcitrant debtor of the 1980s — as an investor favorite and a poster child for the Washington Consensus. "Every time we finished a meeting, the orders would come," the country's deputy secretary of finance Miguel Kiguel recalled. "People were desperate to buy Argentina."
Subsequent research on the emerging market borrowing of the 1990s has confirmed that past defaulters again did not face higher risk premiums than those with an unblemished record. As for the consequences of Argentina's default, the reputation hypothesis would lead us to expect a complete cutoff from all sources of foreign financing after December 2001. But while the government did lose access to international capital markets, it was still able to raise significant amounts of foreign credit through domestic bond auctions. After the debt restructuring of 2005, demand for Argentine bonds was so strong that the riesgo país — the risk premium charged by investors compared to U.S. Treasury bills — converged with Brazil's, which did not default on its debts. In fact, as soon as the restructuring was completed, the riesgo país that had plagued Argentina throughout its crisis returned to the levels previously experienced at the peak of the financial euphoria in 1997. More recently, in 2017, the right-wing Macri government re-entered international capital markets by issuing $2.75 billion worth in unprecedented 100-year bonds immediately after settling the country's long-standing legal dispute with U.S. vulture funds, raising widespread concerns that international investors might once again be overlooking Argentina's patchy repayment record.
The story is no different for Greece. Instead of taking into account the country's long-standing reputation as a "serial defaulter," which suspended payments in every single prewar lending cycle and spent roughly half of its existence as an independent nation in a state of default, financial markets provided the Greek government with almost the exact same borrowing costs as Germany as late as 2008, its risk spread only rising above 1 percent following the collapse of Lehman Brothers and the bankruptcy of Dubai. It was not until the announcement by Prime Minister George Papandreou in late 2009 that the previous government had been cooking the books, and that Greece's real deficit and debt load were much higher than previously thought, that the Greek-German risk spread began to widen dramatically. This appears to indicate that lenders were never really driven by Greece's long-term repayment record; rather, they based their investment decisions on short-term risk assessments. For years, until the global financial crisis of 2008–2009, investors appeared to reason that all debt in the Eurozone carried more or less the same default risk. As a result, Greece, with its perceived high growth potential, developed into an investor favorite, just as Mexico and Argentina had before it, and began to attract large amounts of credit in spite of its history of default — which is exactly the opposite of what the reputation hypothesis would lead us to expect.
It is perhaps not surprising, then, that subsequent research has cast significant doubt on the original reputation hypothesis. In a later study, published a decade and a half after his seminal contribution with Gersovitz, Jonathan Eaton was forced to acknowledge that the evidence to support his earlier theoretical paper was "ambiguous" at best. While a number of scholars have since sought to resuscitate the reputational framework by relaxing some of its most stringent assumptions, even proponents of this line of argument now admit that empirical support for this explanation is mixed and that most research of the past three decades finds the default premiums in sovereign credit markets to be negligible. To the extent that governments do pay higher interest rates after a default, most scholars would agree that these costs tend to be short-lived, ranging from a few months to about two years.
Many of these subsequent empirical refutations were already foreshadowed in an influential theoretical paper by Jeremy Bulow and Kenneth Rogoff published at the end of the 1980s, in which the authors pointed out that countries actually have other ways of insuring themselves against adverse shocks on the economy. Instead of repaying to retain access to international capital markets, a self-interested borrower could simply repudiate its obligations and invest the money it saves on interest payments in foreign capital markets, which — assuming sufficiently high returns — would provide a more profitable cushion for bad times. As a result, the reputational mechanism, hinging entirely on the debtors' need to retain credit access for future consumption smoothing, simply collapses. To have any effect at all, Reinhart and Rogoff conclude, "the reputation approach therefore requires some discipline."
Sanctions: Asset Seizures, Trade Embargoes, and Gunboat Diplomacy
Building on Bulow and Rogoff 's contribution, a second body of literature has proposed direct punishment as the main enforcement mechanism of debtor compliance. By imposing or threatening to impose sanctions, scholars in this tradition argue, private lenders and creditor states can directly coerce recalcitrant debtors to repay. Such creditor sanctions could take either of two forms: the seizure of a debtor's assets abroad, or the imposition of a trade embargo. Subsequent work has also highlighted the historical importance of so-called supersanctions, where external financial control, military coercion and the threat of outright occupation served as the principal enforcement mechanisms. What these different types of sanctions have in common is that they all seek, through some form of direct creditor action, to "raise the cost of default sufficiently high to make repaying the foreign obligations in the self-interest of the sovereign debtor." Like the reputation hypothesis, the sanctions approach therefore remains firmly within the boundaries of neoclassical cost-benefit analysis and rational choice theory. "In this sense," Reinhart and Rogoff note, "the reputation and legal approaches are not so different."
In the legal approach, schematically represented in figure 1.3, sovereign borrowers will do almost anything to avoid default because of the danger of lawsuits inflicting further damage on an already strained national economy. Since historically most emerging market and developing country debt has been denominated in foreign currencies and contracted in other legal jurisdictions, debtors have generally been liable to the laws of the country where the debt was issued (although this is now slowly changing, as emerging markets in particular have begun to issue more debt domestically and in their own currencies). The legal sanctions hypothesis holds that there is therefore no way for the borrower to protect itself from aggressive litigation pursued by creditors inside the issuing country. Selective default, discriminating between domestic and foreign creditors, is generally not an option either, especially in the case of securitized bond finance, where secondary markets add a veil of anonymity to bond holdings and where a suspension of payments is likely to trigger cross-default clauses. The notorious example of the U.S. vulture fund Elliot Associates buying up Peru's greatly depreciated postdefault bonds far below par, and then suing the government for its refusal to repay the face value, is often cited as an exemplary case of aggressive litigation bearing fruit for the persistent speculator. After Elliot succeeded in attaching some of Peru's foreign assets, including a Brady bonds payment that was to be channeled through a Brussels-based clearing house, Peru found itself forced to settle and repay part of its defaulted debt.
Excerpted from Why Not Default? by Jerome Roos. Copyright © 2019 Princeton University Press. Excerpted by permission of PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.
„Über diesen Titel“ kann sich auf eine andere Ausgabe dieses Titels beziehen.
EUR 12,53 für den Versand von USA nach Deutschland
Versandziele, Kosten & DauerEUR 4,66 für den Versand von Vereinigtes Königreich nach Deutschland
Versandziele, Kosten & DauerAnbieter: ThriftBooks-Dallas, Dallas, TX, USA
Hardcover. Zustand: As New. No Jacket. Pages are clean and are not marred by notes or folds of any kind. ~ ThriftBooks: Read More, Spend Less 1.95. Artikel-Nr. G0691180105I2N00
Anzahl: 1 verfügbar
Anbieter: ThriftBooks-Dallas, Dallas, TX, USA
Hardcover. Zustand: Very Good. No Jacket. Missing dust jacket; May have limited writing in cover pages. Pages are unmarked. ~ ThriftBooks: Read More, Spend Less 1.95. Artikel-Nr. G0691180105I4N01
Anzahl: 1 verfügbar
Anbieter: Powell's Bookstores Chicago, ABAA, Chicago, IL, USA
Zustand: Used - Very Good. 2019. hardcover. Cloth, dj. Minor scuffing to jacket. Else clean copy. Very Good. Artikel-Nr. S76394
Anzahl: 1 verfügbar
Anbieter: Wonder Book, Frederick, MD, USA
Zustand: As New. Like New condition. Very Good dust jacket. A near perfect copy that may have very minor cosmetic defects. Artikel-Nr. C09A-03139
Anzahl: 1 verfügbar
Anbieter: PBShop.store UK, Fairford, GLOS, Vereinigtes Königreich
HRD. Zustand: New. New Book. Shipped from UK. Established seller since 2000. Artikel-Nr. WP-9780691180106
Anzahl: 15 verfügbar
Anbieter: moluna, Greven, Deutschland
Zustand: New. KlappentextrnrnHow creditors came to wield unprecedented power over heavily indebted countries-and the dangers this poses to democracyThe European debt crisis has rekindled long-standing debates about the power of finance and the fraught relatio. Artikel-Nr. 251520286
Anzahl: Mehr als 20 verfügbar
Anbieter: PBShop.store US, Wood Dale, IL, USA
HRD. Zustand: New. New Book. Shipped from UK. Established seller since 2000. Artikel-Nr. WP-9780691180106
Anzahl: 15 verfügbar
Anbieter: Majestic Books, Hounslow, Vereinigtes Königreich
Zustand: New. Artikel-Nr. 384350680
Anzahl: 1 verfügbar
Anbieter: AHA-BUCH GmbH, Einbeck, Deutschland
Buch. Zustand: Neu. Neuware - How creditors came to wield unprecedented power over heavily indebted countries-and the dangers this poses to democracyThe European debt crisis has rekindled long-standing debates about the power of finance and the fraught relationship between capitalism and democracy in a globalized world. Why Not Default unravels a striking puzzle at the hea. Artikel-Nr. 9780691180106
Anzahl: 2 verfügbar
Anbieter: Kennys Bookstore, Olney, MD, USA
Zustand: New. 2019. Hardcover. . . . . . Books ship from the US and Ireland. Artikel-Nr. V9780691180106
Anzahl: Mehr als 20 verfügbar