Maintaining G.S. Maddala’s brilliant expository style of cutting through the technical superstructure to reveal only essential details, while retaining the nerve centre of the subject matter, Professor Kajal Lahiri has brought forward this new edition of one of the most important textbooks in its field.
The new edition continues to provide a large number of worked examples, and some shorter data sets. Further data sets and additional supplementary material to assist both the student and lecturer are available on the companion website www.wileyeurope.com/college/maddala
Die Inhaltsangabe kann sich auf eine andere Ausgabe dieses Titels beziehen.
G.S.Maddala was one of the leading figures in field of econometrics for more than 30 years until he passed away in 1999. At the time of his death, he held the University Eminent Scholar Professorship in the Department of Economics at Ohio State University. His previous affiliations include Stanford University, University of Rochester and University of Florida.
Kajal Lahiri is Distinguished Professor of Economics, and Health Policy, and Management and Behaviour at the State University of New York, Albany where he is also Director of the Econometric Research Institute. Professor Lahiri is an Honorary Fellow of the International Institute of Forecasters.
Maintaining G.S. Maddala’s brilliant expository style of cutting through the technical superstructure to reveal only essential details, while retaining the nerve centre of the subject matter, Professor Kajal Lahiri has brought forward this new edition of one of the most important textbooks in its field.
The new edition continues to provide a large number of worked examples, and some shorter data sets. Further data sets and additional supplementary material to assist both the student and lecturer are available on the companion website www.wileyeurope.com/college/maddala
New features for the fourth edition:
What is in this Chapter?
This chapter explains the scope and methodology of econometrics. Econometrics deals with the application of statistical tools to economic data. The first task an econometrician faces is that of formulating an economic relationship, which is necessarily a simplified model of the real-world process. Estimation and testing of these models with observed data and the use of the estimated models for prediction and policy analysis are the other two major goals of econometrics.
This chapter also contains a schematic depiction of the various methodological steps involved in an econometric analysis.
1.1 What is Econometrics?
Literally speaking, the word "econometrics" means "measurement in economics." This is too broad a definition to be of any use, because most of economics is concerned with measurement. We measure our gross national product, employment, money supply, exports, imports, price indexes, and so on. What we mean by econometrics is:
The application of statistical and mathematical methods to the analysis of economic data, with the purpose of giving empirical content to economic theories and verifying them or refuting them.
In this respect, econometrics is distinguished from mathematical economics, which consists of the application of mathematics only, and the theories derived need not necessarily have an empirical content.
The application of statistical tools to economic data has a very long history. Stigler (1954) notes that the first "empirical" demand schedule was published in 1699 by Charles Davenant, and that the first modern statistical demand studies were made by Rodulfo Enini, an Italian statistician, in 1907. The main impetus to the development of econometrics, however, came with the establishment of the Econometric Society in 1930 and the publication of the journal Econometrica in January 1933.
Before any statistical analysis with economic data can be done, one needs a clear mathematical formulation of the relevant economic theory. To take a very simple example, saying that the demand curve is downward sloping is not enough. We have to write the statement in mathematical form. This can be done in several ways. For instance, defining q as the quantity demanded and p as price, we can write
q = [alpha] + p < 0
or
q = [Ap.sup.] < 0
As we will see later in the book, one of the major problems we face is the fact that economic theory is rarely informative about functional forms. We have to use statistical methods to choose the functional form, as well.
1.2 Economic and Econometric Models
The first task an econometrician faces is that of formulating an econometric model. What is a model?
A model is a simplified representation of a real-world process. For instance, saying that the quantity demanded of oranges depends on the price of oranges is a simplified representation, because there are a host of other variables that one can think of that determine the demand for oranges. For instance, income of consumers, an increase in diet consciousness ("drinking coffee causes cancer, so you better switch to orange juice," etc.), an increase or decrease in the price of apples, and so on. However, there is no end to this stream of other variables. In a remote sense, even the price of gasoline can affect the demand for oranges.
Many scientists have argued in favor of simplicity, because simple models are easier to understand, communicate, and test empirically with data. This is the position of Karl Popper (1959, p. 142) and Milton Friedman (1953, p. 14). The choice of a simple model to explain complex real-world phenomena leads to two criticisms:
1. The model is oversimplified.
2. The assumptions are unrealistic.
For instance, in our example of the demand for oranges, to say that it depends only on the price of oranges is an oversimplification and also an unrealistic assumption. To the criticism of oversimplification, one can argue that it is better to start with a simplified model and progressively construct more complicated models. This is the idea expressed by Koopmans (1957, pp. 142-143). On the other hand, there are some who argue in favor of starting with a very general model and simplifying it progressively based on the data available. The famous statistician L. J. (Jimmy) Savage used to say that "a model should be as big as an elephant." Whatever the relative merits of this alternative approach are, we will start with simple models and progressively build more complicated models.
The other criticism we have mentioned is that of "unrealistic assumptions." To this criticism Friedman (1953, pp. 14-15) argues that the assumptions of a theory are never descriptively realistic. He says:
The relevant question to ask about the "assumptions" of a theory is not whether they are descriptively "realistic" for they never are, but whether they are sufficiently good approximations for the purpose at hand. And this question can be answered by only seeing whether the theory works, which means whether it yields sufficiently accurate predictions.
Returning to our example of demand for oranges, to say that it depends only on the price of oranges is a descriptively unrealistic assumption. However, the inclusion of other variables, such as income and price of apples in the model, does not render the model more descriptively realistic. Even this model can be considered to be based on unrealistic assumptions because it leaves out many other variables (such as health consciousness, etc.). But the issue is which model is more useful for predicting the demand for oranges. This issue can be decided only from the data we have and the data we can get.
In practice, we include in our model all the variables that we think are relevant for our purpose and dump the rest of the variables in a basket called "disturbance." This brings us to the distinction between an economic model and an econometric model.
An economic model is a set of assumptions that approximately describes the behavior of an economy (or a sector of an economy). An econometric model consists of the following:
1. A set of behavioral equations derived from the economic model. These equations involve some observed variables and some "disturbances" (which are a catch-all for all the variables considered as irrelevant for the purpose of this model as well as all unforeseen events).
2. A statement of whether there are errors of observation in the observed variables.
3. A specification of the probability distribution of the "disturbances" (and errors of measurement).
With these specifications we can proceed to test the empirical validity of the economic model and use it to make forecasts or use it in policy analysis.
Taking the simplest example of a demand model, the econometric model usually consists of:
1. The behavioral equation
q = [alpha] + p + u
where q is the quantity demanded and p the price. Here p and q are the observed variables and u is a disturbance term.
2. A specification of the probability distribution of u, which says that E(u|p) = 0 and that the values of u for the different observations are independently and normally distributed with mean zero and variance [[sigma].sup.2].
With these specifications one proceeds to test empirically the law of demand or the hypothesis that < 0. One can also use the estimated demand function for prediction and policy purposes.
1.3 The Aims and Methodology of Econometrics
The aims of econometrics are:
1. Formulation of econometric models, that is, formulation of economic models in an empirically testable form. Usually, there are several ways of formulating the econometric model from an economic model, because we have to choose the functional form, the specification of the stochastic structure of the variables, and so on. This part constitutes the specification aspect of the econometric work. 2. Estimation and testing of these models with observed data. This part constitutes the inference aspect of the econometric work. 3. Use of these models for prediction and policy purposes.
During the 1950s and 1960s the inference aspect received a lot of attention and the specification aspect very little. The major preoccupation of econometricians had been the statistical estimation of correctly specified econometric models. During the late 1940s the Cowles Foundation provided a major breakthrough in this respect, but the statistical analysis presented formidable computational problems. Thus the 1950s and 1960s were spent mostly in devising alternative estimation methods and alternative computer algorithms. Not much attention was paid to errors in the specification or to errors in observations. With the advent of high-speed computers, all this has, however, changed. The estimation problems are no longer formidable and econometricians have turned attention to other aspects of econometric analysis.
We can schematically depict the various steps involved in an econometric analysis, as was done before the emphasis on specification analysis. This is shown in Figure 1.1. Since the entries in the boxes are self-explanatory, we will not elaborate on them. The only box that needs an explanation is box 4, "prior information." This refers to any information that we might have on the unknown parameters in the model. This information can come from economic theory or from previous empirical studies.
There has, however, been considerable dissatisfaction with the scheme shown in Figure 1.1. Although one can find instances of dissatisfaction earlier, it was primarily during the 1970s that arguments were levied against the one-way traffic shown in Figure 1.1. We will discuss three of these arguments.
1. In Figure 1.1 there is no feedback from the econometric testing of economic theories to the formulation of economic theories (i.e., from box 6 to box 1). It has been argued that econometricians are not just handmaidens of economic theorists. It is not true that they just take the theories they are given and test them, learning nothing from the tests. So we need an arrow from box 6 to box 1. 2. The same is true regarding the data collection agencies. It is not true that they just gather whatever data they can and the econometricians use whatever data are given them. (The word data comes from the Latin word datum, which means given.) There ought to be feedback from boxes 2 and 5 to box 3. 3. Regarding box 6 itself, it has been argued that the hypothesis testing refers only to the hypotheses suggested by the original economic model. This depends on the assumption that the specification adopted in box 2 is correct. However, what we should be doing is testing the adequacy of the original specification as well. Thus we need an extra box of specification testing and diagnostic checking. There will also be feedback from this box to box 2, that is, the specification tests will result in a new specification for the econometric models. These problems, which have been one of the most important major developments in econometrics in the 1970s, are treated in Chapter 10.
The new developments that have been suggested are shown figuratively in Figure 1.2. Some of the original boxes have been deleted or condensed. The schematic description in Figure 1.2 is illustrative only and should not be interpreted literally. The important things to note are the feedback:
1. From econometric results to economic theory.
2. From specification testing and diagnostic checking to revised specification of the economic model.
3. From the econometric model to data.
In the foregoing scheme we have talked of only one theory, but often there are many competing theories, and one of the main purposes of econometrics is to help in the choice among competing theories. This is the problem of model selection, which is discussed in Chapter 10.
1.4 What Constitutes a Test of an Economic Theory?
Earlier, we stated that one of the aims of econometrics was that of testing economic theories. An important question that arises is: What constitutes a test? As evidence of a successful test of economic theory, it is customary to report that the signs of the estimated coefficients in an econometric model are correct. This approach may be termed the approach of confirming economic theories. The problem with this approach is that, as Mark Blaug (1980, p. 261) points out:
In many areas of economics, different econometric studies reach conflicting conclusions and, given the available data, there are frequently no effective methods for deciding which conclusion is correct. In consequence, contradictory hypotheses continue to co-exist sometimes for decades or more.
A more valid test of an economic theory is if it can give predictions that are better than those of alternative theories suggested earlier. Thus one needs to compare a given model with earlier models. This approach of evaluating alternative theories has received greater attention in recent years. The problems associated with model comparison and model selection are dealt with in Chapter 10.
Summary and an Outline of the Book
The preceding discussion suggests some changes that have taken place during the last decade in the development of econometric methods. The earlier emphasis (during the 1950s and 1960s) was on efficient estimation of a given model. The emphasis has now shifted to specification testing, diagnostic checking, model comparison, and an adequate formulation of the expectational variables, given the pervasive role of expectations in almost all economic theories.
A large part of the book, however, will be devoted to developments that took place in the 1960s and 1970s, because these developments form the basis for recent work. However, many later chapters are devoted to recent advances in the areas of specification testing and model selection in time-series and panel data models. Chapter 16 will deal with some current developments in the area of inference in small samples, including Monte Carlo and bootstrap methods. In addition, the other chapters also describe recent developments. For instance, rational expectations models are discussed in Chapter 13, recent developments on tests for serial correlation are reviewed in Chapter 6, and vector autoregressions, unit roots, and cointegration are discussed in Chapter 14.
The book is divided into three parts:
Part I: Introduction and the Linear Regression Model consists of four chapters. Chapter 2 is a review of basic results in statistics. It also has an introduction to matrix algebra. Further results in matrix algebra on characteristic roots and vectors are in the appendix to Chapter 7. Chapter 3 is on the simple regression model and Chapter 4 is on the multiple regression model. In three specialized appendices to Chapter 4, we introduce nonlinear estimation and large-sample theory, including ML, GIVE, and GMM methods. These chapters cover the basics of regression based on the assumption that the errors are IN(0, [[sigma].sup.2]).
Part II: Violation of the Assumptions of the Basic Model has seven chapters. Chapter 5 is on heteroskedasticity and Chapter 6 is on autocorrelation. Chapter 7 is on multicollinearity. Chapter 8 is on dummy variables and truncated variables. Chapter 9 is on simultaneous equations. Chapter 10 discusses diagnostic checking of the basic linear regression model, specification testing, model selection on nonlinear models, and tests for nonnormality. Chapter 11 is on errors in variables.
These chapters relax the several assumptions made regarding the basic regression model discussed in Part I.
Part III: Special Topics consists of five chapters. Chapter 12 introduces the basic time-series analysis, including ARMA models and the Box-Jenkins approach. Chapter 13 analyzes distributed lags and models of expectations. Chapter 14 is on vector autoregressions, unit roots, and cointegration. Chapter 15 is on the estimation of various panel data models, and Chapter 16 is on small-sample inference and bootstrap methods.
(Continues...)
Excerpted from Introduction to Econometricsby G.S. Maddala Kajal Lahiri Copyright © 2006 by John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Excerpted by permission.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.
„Über diesen Titel“ kann sich auf eine andere Ausgabe dieses Titels beziehen.
EUR 5,74 für den Versand von Vereinigtes Königreich nach Deutschland
Versandziele, Kosten & DauerEUR 4,88 für den Versand von Vereinigtes Königreich nach Deutschland
Versandziele, Kosten & DauerAnbieter: Better World Books Ltd, Dunfermline, Vereinigtes Königreich
Zustand: Good. Ships from the UK. Former library book; may include library markings. Used book that is in clean, average condition without any missing pages. Artikel-Nr. 13732331-6
Anzahl: 3 verfügbar
Anbieter: Anybook.com, Lincoln, Vereinigtes Königreich
Zustand: Good. This is an ex-library book and may have the usual library/used-book markings inside.This book has soft covers. Clean from markings. In good all round condition. Please note the Image in this listing is a stock photo and may not match the covers of the actual item,1300grams, ISBN:9780470015124. Artikel-Nr. 9940367
Anzahl: 1 verfügbar
Anbieter: Anybook.com, Lincoln, Vereinigtes Königreich
Zustand: Poor. This is an ex-library book and may have the usual library/used-book markings inside.This book has soft covers. Book contains highlighter markings. In poor condition, suitable as a reading copy. Please note the Image in this listing is a stock photo and may not match the covers of the actual item,1300grams, ISBN:9780470015124. Artikel-Nr. 8669210
Anzahl: 1 verfügbar
Anbieter: Anybook.com, Lincoln, Vereinigtes Königreich
Zustand: Good. This is an ex-library book and may have the usual library/used-book markings inside.This book has soft covers. Clean from markings. In good all round condition. Please note the Image in this listing is a stock photo and may not match the covers of the actual item,1150grams, ISBN:9780470015124. Artikel-Nr. 9940368
Anzahl: 1 verfügbar
Anbieter: Anybook.com, Lincoln, Vereinigtes Königreich
Zustand: Good. This is an ex-library book and may have the usual library/used-book markings inside.This book has soft covers. Clean from markings. In good all round condition. Please note the Image in this listing is a stock photo and may not match the covers of the actual item,1300grams, ISBN:9780470015124. Artikel-Nr. 9930061
Anzahl: 1 verfügbar
Anbieter: PBShop.store UK, Fairford, GLOS, Vereinigtes Königreich
PAP. Zustand: New. New Book. Shipped from UK. Established seller since 2000. Artikel-Nr. FW-9780470015124
Anzahl: 15 verfügbar
Anbieter: moluna, Greven, Deutschland
Zustand: New. G.S.Maddala was one of the leading figures in field of econometrics for more than 30 years until he passed away in 1999. At the time of his death, he held the University Eminent Scholar Professorship in the Department of Economics at Ohio State University. . Artikel-Nr. 446911209
Anzahl: Mehr als 20 verfügbar
Anbieter: Ria Christie Collections, Uxbridge, Vereinigtes Königreich
Zustand: New. In. Artikel-Nr. ria9780470015124_new
Anzahl: Mehr als 20 verfügbar
Anbieter: Wonder Book, Frederick, MD, USA
Zustand: As New. Like New condition. 4th edition. A near perfect copy that may have very minor cosmetic defects. Artikel-Nr. H17A-03686
Anzahl: 1 verfügbar
Anbieter: AHA-BUCH GmbH, Einbeck, Deutschland
Taschenbuch. Zustand: Neu. Neuware - Now in its fourth edition, this landmark text provides a fresh, accessible and well written introduction to the subject. With a rigorous pedagogical framework, which sets it apart from comparable texts, the latest edition features an expanded website providing numerous real life data sets and examples. Artikel-Nr. 9780470015124
Anzahl: 2 verfügbar